This approach starkly contrasted with the development strategy adopted by many less affluent countries after World War II. Their goal was to create a mass consumer society based on a strong industrial economy—a vision pursued by protecting domestic markets and embracing an active redistributive role for the state.
The capitalist model presumed that open markets and a withdrawal from state-led redistribution of social benefits would cultivate economic sectors, professional environments, and jobs to expand the middle class. Yet the potential for such expansion proved finite.
These constraints were imposed by the very financial and economic system into which post-Soviet countries sought to integrate. The roles allotted to semi-peripheral and peripheral nations within this system were largely fixed.
At the heart of these limitations lies the reality that the leadership and prosperity of some countries directly depend on others occupying less favorable or subordinate positions within the international hierarchy. A nation's place in this hierarchy determines which industries will dominate its economy and how far its development can progress.
Until the 1980s, less affluent nations enjoyed greater mobility in their global economic standing. An alternative system to capitalism allowed these countries to prosper by integrating organically into regional production chains, complementing rather than competing with one another.
In contrast, the capitalist system eliminated the possibility of restructuring the global economy so that each nation could assume its rightful place and receive returns commensurate with its contributions.
Because semi-peripheral and peripheral economies have limited development potential under capitalism, focusing on building a middle class has led to structural imbalances among different segments of their populations.
In non-wealthy countries, the middle class—aspiring to the lifestyles of their Western counterparts—seeks greater gains within a constrained economic environment. This drives fierce competition with other social groups, especially the less affluent.
Often, this escalates into the creation of undemocratic methods for redistributing public resources. By cultivating informal relationships with officials, bureaucrats, and big businesses, they leverage administrative influence to access privileges and sources of rent without facing any competition.
In Kazakhstan, the initial class of rentiers—owners who generate steady income through asset ownership—leveraged their positions within the Soviet-era nomenklatura, along with connections and industry expertise, to acquire resources and assets in sectors ranging from mining and metallurgy to telecommunications. This process is
detailed by researchers Elmira Satybaldieva and Balihar Sanghera in their book Rentier Capitalism and Counter-Movements in Central Asia.
Other rentiers, as political scientist Eric McGlinchey
notes in his book Chaos, Violence, Dynasty, capitalized on their proximity to President Nursultan Nazarbayev's family and participated in patronage networks—elite circles where loyalty to a higher authority in the power structure is rewarded with privileges. In some instances, assets were obtained through fraud, corruption, racketeering, or even outright violence.
Ágnes Gagyi develops this theory from her analysis of middle-class formation in Hungary and Romania. While its applicability to Kazakhstan awaits comprehensive empirical studies,